Even though fair elections are held at regular intervals for State Assemblies and Parliament, they do not reflect the true consent of the people because a large number of women are missing from the electorate
On her arrival in India recently, the words of Gloria Steinem, American
feminist and leader of the women’s liberation movement, sounded like
bells tolling for all women in today’s modern Indian society. “I came
[to India] and what was here a half-a-century ago is still here… and yet
there is everything else.” Studying data on the sex ratio in India over
60 years supports her grim observation. In this essay we provide a
political economy explanation for the persistence of gender inequality
in
Indian society over the long run.
The much debated Women’s Reservation Bill proposes to reserve a third of
all legislature seats for women, at national and State levels in India.
If passed, this Bill would uplift the general mood of the nation which
has been engulfed by a heightened sense of gender inequality over the
last year. Following the brutal rape and murder of a 23-year-old student
of physiotherapy in Delhi last year, there was massive and prolonged
outpouring of public anger across the nation. India has never looked
more unsafe for women. The Bill is going to assuage a hurt population.
It is, however, unlikely to solve the fundamental problem that Indian
women suffer from.
Within a democratic system, policies are implemented by a government
that is formed “by the consent of the governed.” In India, even though
fair elections are held at regular intervals for State Assemblies and
the National Parliament, they do not reflect the true consent of the
people because a large number of women voters are “missing” from the
electorate. We estimate that more than 65 million women (approximately
20 per cent of the female electorate) are missing and, therefore, these
elections reveal the preferences (or the will) of a population that is
artificially skewed against women.
Worsening sex ratio
The phrase “missing women” was coined by Amartya Sen when he showed that in parts of the developing world, the ratio of women to men in the population is suspiciously low. The worsening sex ratio (number of females per 1,000 males) in countries such as India and China reflected the gross neglect of women. He estimated that more than 100 million women were missing due to gender discrimination. It was commonly believed that “boy preference” at birth and the mistreatment of young girls were the main reasons. Some careful and subsequent data work by Anderson and Ray showed that excess female mortality is a more universal phenomenon which holds for all age groups in these countries. They provided detailed decomposition of the missing women by age and cause of death and a particularly sinister observation was that the number of excess female deaths from “intentional injuries” or reported violence was disturbingly high in India.
The phrase “missing women” was coined by Amartya Sen when he showed that in parts of the developing world, the ratio of women to men in the population is suspiciously low. The worsening sex ratio (number of females per 1,000 males) in countries such as India and China reflected the gross neglect of women. He estimated that more than 100 million women were missing due to gender discrimination. It was commonly believed that “boy preference” at birth and the mistreatment of young girls were the main reasons. Some careful and subsequent data work by Anderson and Ray showed that excess female mortality is a more universal phenomenon which holds for all age groups in these countries. They provided detailed decomposition of the missing women by age and cause of death and a particularly sinister observation was that the number of excess female deaths from “intentional injuries” or reported violence was disturbingly high in India.
There is unanimous agreement among experts that this phenomenon is one
of the most momentous problems faced by the developing world in modern
times. The general sense is that it can be corrected by political action
and public policy. It is in that regard that we explore the role of
democracy in solving the missing women’s problem. We analyse Indian
electorate data over 50 years and study whether solutions to this
dangerous trend can emerge from within such a political system.
Using Dr. Sen’s methodology, we compute the sex ratio in the electorate
across all the States in India over 50 years. The electorate includes
all the people who are registered to vote in elections. In the next
step, we use Kerala, the State with the best sex ratio in the
electorate, as a reference for all the States to compute the number of
missing women. This simple analysis throws up three shocking facts.
First, in the last 50 years of Indian democracy, the absolute number of
missing women has increased fourfold from 15 million to 68 million. This
is not merely a reflection of the growth in the overall population,
but, rather, of the fact that this dangerous trend has worsened with
time. As a percentage of the female electorate, missing women have gone
up significantly — from 13 per cent to approximately 20 per cent.
Second, the adverse sex ratio of the electorate in India has not changed
significantly over the last 50 years. In fact, when we look at
different States, we see that it has become worse for most of the large
backward States like Uttar Pradesh, Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra,
and Rajasthan. This disappointing trend means that there are many more
missing women voters in the population. Hence, fewer female voters will
voice their opinions through elections. Political decisions which are
based on election outcomes therefore underrepresent the female
population. They are not a true reflection of the female policy
preferences.
Third, with the exception of a very few States such as Andhra Pradesh
and Kerala, the sex ratio in the electorate is far worse than the
general sex ratio in the population. This means that not all the women
who are eligible to vote in Indian elections are registered to vote and,
therefore, they are missing from the electoral list. In backward States
like Uttar Pradesh and Bihar, this difference is as high as 9.3 and 5.7
percentage points which translated into millions in absolute numbers.
The worsening sex ratio of the Indian electorate has deep and long
lasting consequences given the democratic system of governance. Within a
democracy, politicians compete to get elected and though it is well
recognised that men and women differ in their policy preferences, the
adverse sex ratio of the electorate will make it unlikely that the
preferences of women get significant attention.
Competitive electoral politics
In fact, because of the missing women, the competitive electoral process will perpetuate gender-biased policies in India. The problem here is that the politicians respond to the preferences of the existing electorate in the population and not to the counterfactual.
In fact, because of the missing women, the competitive electoral process will perpetuate gender-biased policies in India. The problem here is that the politicians respond to the preferences of the existing electorate in the population and not to the counterfactual.
If the 65 million missing women were present within the electorate, they
would have an important influence in shaping government policies. What
is troubling in a democratic system of governance is that even if a
politician is not biased against women in his policy preferences, the
electoral competition will ensure that he chooses policies in favour of
his average electorate which is increasingly male-dominated in India.
This is why gender-biased practices and policies will be perpetuated
over the long run in a democratic system like India’s unless there is an
exogenous shock to this system.
This problem is akin to a market failure for democracy. Indeed, this
could potentially explain why the existing political framework is
inadequately equipped to address this pressing concern and why gender
bias has persisted in Indian society. It is also not surprising that
even though India has had a very good track record of holding regular
elections and a democratic form of government, it remains one of worst
performers in the Gender Inequality Index (GII) of the World Bank. The
GII captures the loss in achievement within a country due to gender
inequality and is based on measures of health, labour force
participation and empowerment. In the Human Development Report, 2012,
India performs more poorly than neighbouring Pakistan in the GII despite
having a higher per capita income and a democratic government. More
strikingly, it is ranked 133rd out of 146 countries and even lags behind
war-torn countries such as Iraq and Sudan.
Mixed results
To what extent, then, can women’s reservation in Parliament and the State Assemblies address the gender bias problem in India? In our opinion, this will have a very limited impact. The underlying assumption with the Women’s Reservation Bill is that women as policymakers are more sensitive to women-related issues. However, it is crucial to note that India has experimented with women’s reservation at the level of the panchayat or village councils since the mid-1990s. This has generated very interesting research on whether women’s reservation has had any impact on the allocation of resources towards women. So far, the evidence from this experiment is mixed — some find evidence in favour of a positive impact while others do not find any impact of this reservation.
To what extent, then, can women’s reservation in Parliament and the State Assemblies address the gender bias problem in India? In our opinion, this will have a very limited impact. The underlying assumption with the Women’s Reservation Bill is that women as policymakers are more sensitive to women-related issues. However, it is crucial to note that India has experimented with women’s reservation at the level of the panchayat or village councils since the mid-1990s. This has generated very interesting research on whether women’s reservation has had any impact on the allocation of resources towards women. So far, the evidence from this experiment is mixed — some find evidence in favour of a positive impact while others do not find any impact of this reservation.
The impact of the reservation, I believe, will depend on the exact
nature of the reservation policy. For example, if seats are reserved on a
quick rotation basis then there might be no long-term policies
favouring women and thereby having minimal impact. On the other hand, if
seats are reserved for a certain number of election rounds then the
impact would depend on the basis of the reservation at the constituency
level. Here, we are inclined to propose a reservation policy based on
the gender ratio in the constituency — reserve those seats where the
gender ratio of women to men is the worst. The fundamental reason for
this is that an adverse gender ratio is a measure of neglect of women in
that society. So, if the objective of women’s reservation is
“compensatory justice” then it should start with those constituencies
where the neglect is the highest.
The competitive electoral process, however, is likely to undo the impact
of any women’s reservation policy. The logic of this is that if both
men and women have equal rights to vote, then even in reserved
constituencies where there are fewer women compared to men, women
political candidates who compete with each other to get themselves
elected might choose policies which favour men. Once again, the
competitive electoral process even in the presence of women’s
reservation, might perpetuate gender-biased policies.
In a nutshell, the competitive electoral process in Indian democracy
with or without women’s reservation will fail to deliver policies that
are not gender-biased. In the presence of missing women, whose consent
cannot be taken into account in the electoral process, democracy will
fail to deliver policies that promote women’s welfare (especially in
those situations where there is a divergence in opinion between men and
women). India can begin to address this disaster by first recognising
that an adverse gender ratio is a human rights problem which is an
outcome of the sustained, gross neglect of women. And the solution for
this lies outside the competitive democratic system.
(The writers are professors at the Indian School of Business.)
Comments
Post a Comment